Cover EconPol Opinion blanco 2018

CAP Beyond 2020: Seven More Years of Money for Nothing?

Friedrich Heinemann and Stefani Weiss

In recent months, the likely contours of post-2020 Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) have emerged. Following a first communication in November 2017, in June 2018 the Commission published its proposals for CAP beyond 2020. These cautious reform ideas have set the parameters for the coming negotiations: CAP will continue to have a two-pillar structure of direct payments and rural development, with a seven-year budget of €365 billion (current prices). As before, almost three-quarters of the budget is reserved for direct payments to farmers (€265 billion).

While the size of the CAP budget has received a lot of attention, unfortunately, the Commission’s ideas for the contents of the policy have so far hardly met with large interest. This is a fundamentally misguided reception. The whole idea of “European added value” – the Leitmotif for the new EU budget – must urgently be applied to CAP as it will absorb such a substantial budget share. From an added value-perspective, this CAP is only acceptable if it can realistically produce a significant amount of European public goods. A recent joint study by the Bertelsmann Stiftung and the Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW) has now looked into the Commission proposals and developed recommendations how direct payments could be justified at such a considerable level in future.

Direct payments do not contribute to higher fairness in distribution

Searching for the “European added value” of CAP is a tricky issue. There is a growing consensus that direct payment to farmers do not make sense as a social policy tool. First of all, it is hard to see why farmers are a particularly needy or deserving group in society whose standards for minimum income protection should be privileged compared to that of other groups in the society. Apart from that, already by construction, direct payments are highly imprecise in terms of social targeting. They lack an individual income test that takes account of a farmer’s full income – from all sources. Moreover, the amount of payment is determined only by the farm’s size in hectares. Bertelsmann Stiftung-ZEW calculations compare the size of average direct payments per farm with a country-specific level of income support that takes account of the (large) income differentials across member states. The results show that for the majority of member states, direct payments to the average farm are either too high or too low. Hence, it is impossible to argue that direct payments have a European added value in terms of a fairer or more precise income distribution. On the contrary, from the viewpoint of equitable redistribution, the added value is negative, since Member States could reach the social objectives with much higher precision and sectoral neutrality.

Direct payments in exchange for public goods: the false alibi

This leaves a second and more substantive argument to legitimize CAP: Direct payments must be seen (and constructed) as a compensation for farmers who produce European public goods related to the climate, the environment or to animal protection. This “public good narrative” has become dominant in current attempts to legitimize the high subsidies for farmers. However, the broad use of the new narrative must not be confounded with actual substance. Overwhelming evidence shows that the greening conditions related to 30 percent of direct payments in the current MFF have not incentivized any significant protection of the environment, climate or animal welfare above the legally binding standards. In this sense, the greening conditions have so far been not much more but an alibi to disguise the unconditional flow of funds to farmers.

Commission proposal: The downside of flexibility and simplification

Would the Commission proposal for the CAP beyond 2020 be more effective to make farmers provide public goods to the community? This appears to be highly unlikely without substantial changes to the current plan. On the contrary, the following aspects in the proposal point to an even weaker link between direct payments and environmental public goods than before:

  • Increasing flexibility: the Commission promises member states more flexibility how to use direct payments. This hardly sounds like binding conditions on the provision of (uniformly defined) European public goods. Rather, this could invite member states to cherry pick those tools that are easy for their farmers to apply for and to maximize windfall gains for their own agricultural sector.
  • Race to the bottom: increasing flexibility for member states has severe potential consequences. It might induce a race to the bottom of member states’ environmental ambitions. Truly ambitious member states that use all of the available triggers to force farmers towards environmental and animal protection standards above the EU average will impose a competitive disadvantage on their domestic farmers.
  • Simplification: although it is desirable to cut red tape, the Commission’s promise of “simplification” is ambiguous. An effective public good conditionality must impose a costly burden on farmers. It is precisely the existence of that burden for which farmers earn payments. From this perspective, the Commission’s promise to simplify could, in part, be interpreted as a surrender to lobby pressure for unconditional transfers.

In sum, the current state of affairs does not give cause for optimism about a move towards real European added value in direct payments. If no substantive corrections occur in the ongoing legislative process, the post-2020 CAP will constitute a step backwards, making direct payments even less effective in incentivizing public good provision.

Eco-schemes with a precise value-for-money logic point the way forward

However, the Commission proposal itself offers a remedy. The proposal includes the so called “eco-schemes”. This instrument follows the logic of compensating farmers for services that they provide to society. Explicitly, compensation is only paid for services above the mandatory re-quirements. If these instruments are developed towards a price tag to a well-defined public good provision they could lead to a breakthrough. For greenhouse-gas-emission reductions, for example, reference prices do exist from European emission trading, and provide a hint for an adequate compensation. For other public goods – such as caring for higher quality animal life or for ecologically sustainable use of farmland – the unit price could be based on the costs function of farms producing at the efficient frontier.

Necessarily, the public good approach requires extensive reporting requirements and verification. The provision of contractual environmental services to society must be evidenced as in any other field of public procurement. As explained, “simplicity” of direct payments in the sense of cutting back bureaucracy is not an objective in itself from the public good perspective.

Besides a clearer price-logic of eco-schemes a second modification to the Commission proposal is required: Member States must not be allowed to determine the share of direct payments invested in eco-schemes. Voluntariness would kick-off a race to the bottom. Farmers in ecologically ambitious countries would be disadvantaged against competitors in countries that largely transfer direct payments as unconditional lump sums.

The “European added value”-logic is at stake

Obviously, farm lobby groups will fight against that strict pricing logic. This is a perfectly rational reaction from their side: windfall gains from lump sum transfers create greater welfare for recipients than payments in exchange for the costly provision of public goods. Strong political leadership is required to resist that pressure for unconditional transfers. If farmers’ lobbies succeed in this struggle, Europe will spend more than €250 billion on direct payments in 2021–2027 without significant provision of public goods in return. This would become another striking case in which European added value rhetoric stands in sharp contrast to the facts on the ground. In this sense, seven more years of money for nothing is a wasteful though realistic outcome of the coming final negotiations on CAP direct payments.

 

Friedrich Heinemann is head of department “Corporate Taxation and Public Finance” at the Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW) in Mannheim.

Stefani Weiss is Senior Expert at Bertelsmann Stiftung in Brussels.

 

Citation

Friedrich Heinemann and Stefani Weiss, "CAP Beyond 2020: Seven More Years of Money for Nothing?", EconPol Europe Opinion 11, October 2018.